52 pages • 1 hour read
Daron Acemoglu, James A. RobinsonA modern alternative to SparkNotes and CliffsNotes, SuperSummary offers high-quality Study Guides with detailed chapter summaries and analysis of major themes, characters, and more.
Chapter 4 explores how small institutional differences can lead to divergent paths of development during major events or changes in history, called critical junctures. The Black Death was one such critical juncture, and it had profound and lasting impacts on societal institutions in Western and Eastern Europe.
The Black Death, which struck Europe in the 14th century, devastated populations and challenged the feudal system. The pandemic led to a scarcity of labor, empowering peasants to demand better conditions. In Western Europe, this led to the dissolution of feudalism and the rise of a more inclusive labor market with rising wages. In contrast, Eastern Europe responded by intensifying feudal controls in what became known as the “Second Serfdom,” further entrenching extractive institutions.
This divergence between Western and Eastern Europe highlights how small pre-existing differences in institutions can lead to different outcomes when societies encounter critical junctures. These institutional differences, although minor initially, accumulate over time through a process of “institutional drift,” leading to significant divergences in societal development.
The chapter also discusses the role of contingency in history. For instance, England’s development of inclusive institutions was not preordained but was contingent on various factors, including its victory over the Spanish Armada, which was far from guaranteed. This victory was crucial in allowing England to participate in Atlantic trade, setting the stage for the political revolutions that eventually led to more inclusive institutions. Further, the expansion of Atlantic trade in the 17th century led to different outcomes in various European countries, influenced by their respective institutional frameworks. England, with its relatively weak monarchy, was able to develop more pluralistic institutions, whereas in France and Spain, where monarchs had tighter control, absolutism was reinforced.
Institutional drift and critical junctures also explain the varied paths of other regions, including Latin America, Africa, the Middle East, and Asia. Colonization and decolonization further shaped these regions’ trajectories, often reinforcing extractive institutions.
Chapter 5 examines growth under extractive institutions, using the Soviet Union and other historical examples to illustrate how such growth is typically unsustainable and often leads to collapse.
The Soviet Union experienced rapid industrial growth under Joseph Stalin’s regime. This growth, however, was not based on technological innovation but on reallocating resources from agriculture to industry, often through brutal means. While this approach led to significant initial growth, it was inherently unsustainable due to the lack of incentives for innovation and technological progress. The Soviet growth model eventually ran out of steam, illustrating the limitations of extractive institutions.
Probing deeper into the Soviet example, the chapter highlights how the centralized control under Stalin’s regime led to a distorted economic landscape where incentives for innovation and efficiency were severely lacking. This centralization focused on rapid industrialization, often at the cost of agricultural productivity and human welfare. The Soviet model was marked by forced labor, collectivization of agriculture, and a high degree of state intervention in all economic activities. While this resulted in impressive initial economic growth figures and industrial development, it failed to foster an environment conducive to sustained innovation and technological advancement. The lack of a market-based incentive structure meant that once the initial gains from reallocating resources were exhausted, the economy stagnated. This phenomenon is not unique to the Soviet Union; it is a common characteristic of growth under extractive institutions, where the emphasis is on immediate gains rather than long-term sustainable development.
The Maya civilization is another example. The Maya city-states developed through extractive institutions that centralized power and wealth in the hands of a ruling elite. However, this system also led to internal conflicts and power struggles, ultimately resulting in the collapse of the civilization.
While extractive institutions can generate economic growth, this growth is typically limited, not based on innovation, and unsustainable in the long run. It is often characterized by a lack of creative destruction, limited technological progress, and internal conflicts over control of wealth and resources.
By contrast, growth under inclusive institutions is more sustainable and driven by technological innovation and creative destruction. The chapter concludes by suggesting that China, experiencing rapid economic growth under an extractive regime, might face similar challenges unless it transitions to more inclusive political institutions.
The authors explore the historical development of Venice and its transformation from a rich, inclusive society to a stagnant, extractive one, and how this parallels the broader patterns of institutional evolution around the world.
Venice, a hub of Mediterranean trade in the Middle Ages, initially thrived due to inclusive economic institutions such as the commenda, a form of joint stock company crucial for social mobility and economic expansion. Economic inclusiveness pressured the political system to open up, leading to political reforms. The doge (chief magistrate) was elected for life by the General Assembly, a group dominated by powerful families, but over time, the doge’s power was curtailed to prevent absolute rule.
However, the success and wealth generated by Venice’s inclusive institutions eventually led to their downfall. The established elites, threatened by the rise of new wealthy families, began to close off the system to preserve their own power and wealth. This process, known as “La Serrata” (The Closure), effectively transformed Venice into a hereditary aristocracy, halting social mobility and leading to political and economic stagnation.
The turning point was the 1297 decision that automatically nominated members of the Great Council who had served in the past four years, effectively sealing it off to outsiders and marking the start of Venice’s decline. This political closure was soon followed by economic restrictions, including the banning of the commenda and the monopolization of long-distance trade by the nobility. These changes marked a shift toward more extractive economic institutions, leading to a decline in Venice’s prosperity.
Just as Venice’s early inclusive institutions were reversed, similar patterns were observed in ancient Rome and other civilizations. While historical factors influence institutional development, there is no predetermined cumulative process. Critical junctures, like the Black Death in Europe, interact with existing institutional differences to create divergent paths. The Roman Empire’s fall, for instance, led to a decentralized feudal order in Europe. The rise of inclusive institutions and subsequent industrial growth in England did not directly stem from Roman or earlier institutions. Instead, it resulted from critical junctures and small differences in institutions. England’s divergence was historically rooted but not predetermined, highlighting the complex interplay between historical events and institutional evolution.
Chapter 4 directly engages with the theme of The Role of Institutions in Economic Development, demonstrating how events like the Black Death influenced the evolution of economic institutions and, consequently, the economic fate of societies. This chapter utilizes historical examples to argue that institutions shape economic outcomes at such flash points in history. The comparison between the consequences of the Black Death in Western and Eastern Europe provides an illustration of how the same event can lead to vastly different outcomes in different regions based on pre-existing institutional structures. The Black Death is presented as an example of a critical juncture to show how small differences in institutions can lead to divergent societal developments during major events or changes in history. The chapter also emphasizes the concept of institutional drift, where minor differences accumulate over time, leading to significant divergences. The chapter illustrates this concept through historical events like the expansion of Atlantic trade and the Industrial Revolution, which led to different institutional responses in different regions.
Chapter 5 examines the limitations of growth under extractive institutions, arguing that while such systems can generate initial economic growth, it is inherently unsustainable due to the lack of incentives for innovation and technological progress: “Extractive institutions, by their very logic, must create wealth so that it can be extracted” (125). This statement crystallizes the essence of extractive institutions. It emphasizes their primary function, which is to generate wealth for the ruling elite, not for societal welfare. This understanding of extractive institutions is crucial to grasp the dynamics of such systems and their impact on economic growth and societal development. The narrative uses historical examples, such as the Soviet Union’s focus on reallocating resources without fostering innovation, as an analogy for the broader limitations of extractive institutions. This chapter illuminates the theme of The Impact of Political Systems on National Prosperity, showcasing how the Soviet Union’s political system, characterized by extractive institutions, ultimately hindered sustainable economic growth.
Chapter 6 highlights the historical development of Venice to explore the theme of The Historical Evolution of Economic and Political Structures. The chapter chronicles how the city-state transitioned from a prosperous, inclusive society to a stagnant, extractive one, and uses this transition as a metaphor for broader patterns of institutional evolution. The story of Venice’s rise and fall provides a powerful narrative to illustrate the dynamic nature of institutional change over time and its impact on a society’s economic trajectory.
The literary and rhetorical elements used in these chapters contribute to the text’s persuasive power. The authors integrate historical anecdotes into their analysis to offer a nuanced perspective on the factors contributing to economic disparity among nations. For instance, the quote “The massive scarcity of labor created by the plague shook the foundations of the feudal order. It encouraged peasants to demand that things change” illustrates how a critical juncture can catalyze societal and economic transformation (99). Similarly, the quote “The economic expansion of Venice, which created more pressure for political change, exploded after the changes in political and economic institutions that followed the murder of the doge in 1171” highlights the relationship between economic growth and political upheaval in Venice’s history (154). These narratives provide depth and context to the book’s discussion of economic disparity, emphasizing the role of political decisions and historical contingencies in shaping economic institutions. By weaving historical events into the narrative, the book makes a case for the importance of understanding institutional dynamics in assessing a nation’s economic potential.