logo

60 pages 2 hours read

Richard H. Thaler

Misbehaving

Nonfiction | Book | Adult | Published in 2016

A modern alternative to SparkNotes and CliffsNotes, SuperSummary offers high-quality Study Guides with detailed chapter summaries and analysis of major themes, characters, and more.

Parts 2-3Chapter Summaries & Analyses

Part 2, Chapter 7 Summary: “Mental Accounting”

Thaler explores the concept of mental accounting, a term he adopted from Daniel Kahneman and Amos Tversky. Mental accounting is essentially how people think about money and categorize their expenses. Thaler emphasizes the significance of mental accounting in understanding consumer behavior, noting that it’s a fundamental aspect of his career’s work.

Thaler explains that traditional economic theory views consumer decisions through the lens of opportunity costs, considering the alternative uses of time and money. However, he argues this approach is too complex for the average consumer. People don’t usually engage in such extensive analysis for everyday decisions, as it’s impractical and overwhelming. Instead, they use mental accounting, which simplifies financial decision-making.

He introduces two types of utility in mental accounting: acquisition utility and transaction utility. Acquisition utility aligns with standard economic theory, where consumer surplus is the utility of the object gained minus the opportunity cost. Transaction utility, on the other hand, is based on the deal’s perceived quality. It’s the difference between the actual price paid and the reference price (the price one expects to pay). This concept explains why people feel differently about the same product based on where or how they buy it, like paying more for a beer at a resort than at a grocery store.

Thaler’s research involved interviewing families to understand their financial decision-making processes. He discovered people don’t consider every possible use of money for each decision. Instead, they simplify the process using mental accounting. For instance, a sale price can create a sense of transaction utility, even if the item wasn’t necessary.

Part 2, Chapter 8 Summary: “Sunk Costs”

Thaler examines the concept of sunk costs, a common financial fallacy where people continue an endeavor due to the number of resources already invested, regardless of future costs or benefits. Thaler uses various real-life examples to illustrate how people often irrationally allow sunk costs to influence their decisions.

For instance, Vince, a tennis club member, continued to play despite developing tennis elbow, driven by the desire not to waste his membership fee. This is a classic example of the sunk cost fallacy, where the initial investment overshadows the current negative utility or pain.

Thaler also discusses a personal story involving his friend Joyce and her daughter Cindy. Joyce insisted Cindy wear dresses she had bought for her, despite Cindy’s preference for pants. Thaler explains to Joyce the money spent on dresses is a sunk cost and should not influence Cindy’s clothing choice. Joyce is relieved to hear this, as it resolves her guilt over “wasting” money on unworn dresses.

These scenarios highlight a common struggle with sunk costs, where individuals feel compelled to get their money’s worth out of an investment, even if it leads to unfavorable outcomes. Thaler emphasizes this behavior is not just limited to small personal decisions but can also be seen in larger contexts, like corporate investments or even military strategies.

Part 2, Chapter 9 Summary: “Buckets and Budgets”

Thaler discusses the concept of mental accounting, focusing on how individuals and organizations use budgeting rules to manage finances. The author highlights how households, particularly those on tight budgets, often divide their money into different categories or “buckets,” such as rent, food, and utilities. This method, which can involve physical envelopes or jars for different expenses, is a way to exercise control over spending and ensure essential costs are covered.

Thaler points out that while this approach helps in managing finances, it violates the economic principle of fungibility, where money should be interchangeable and not restricted to specific uses. For instance, excess funds from a utility budget could be used for other needs, but mental accounting often prevents this transfer of funds.

Organizations similarly allocate budgets to different departments, but this can lead to inefficient spending, as funds in one category can’t be reallocated to meet urgent needs in another. This inflexibility highlights how mental accounting can lead to suboptimal financial decisions.

Thaler also explores how mental accounting impacts personal spending behaviors. For example, people are more willing to spend “budgeted” money, like a weekly entertainment allowance, but hesitate to draw from savings accounts. This behavior can lead to paradoxical situations, like carrying high-interest credit card debt while having funds in low-interest savings accounts.

The chapter concludes with a discussion on how mental accounting affects perceptions of wealth. Different “accounts” such as cash, checking accounts, and long-term savings are treated with varying degrees of spending reluctance. Thaler suggests understanding and occasionally bypassing these mental accounting rules can lead to more rational financial decisions.

Part 2, Chapter 10 Summary: “At the Poker Table”

Thaler explores the psychology of gambling, particularly in the context of poker and how it relates to mental accounting. Thaler, observing a regular low-stakes poker game among Cornell economics faculty, notes players’ behavior often changed depending on whether they were winning or losing. This is intriguing because the amount won or lost was relatively insignificant compared to the players’ overall net worth. The key insight is that losses in the “poker mental account” only influenced behavior within the context of the game itself.

Thaler connects this observation to Kahneman and Tversky’s prospect theory, which suggests people are risk-seeking when dealing with losses. However, he finds this explanation incomplete, as it doesn’t account for why players prefer small bets with slim winning chances over larger, more rational bets. His experiences indicated players who were behind were more attracted to bets with a small chance for a big win and were averse to larger bets that increased their potential loss.

This behavior extends beyond the poker table to casinos, where gamblers treat winnings as “the house’s money,” leading to a more relaxed attitude toward risk. Thaler worked with Eric Johnson to conduct lab experiments, replicating these observations under ethical conditions. Their findings revealed people exhibited risk-seeking behavior when they perceived themselves as playing with “house money” or trying to break even.

These insights into mental accounting and risk behavior have broader implications, influencing financial markets and investment behaviors. During financial bubbles, investors often risk recent gains, perceiving them as less valuable “house money.” Similarly, mutual fund managers and rogue traders have been observed to take greater risks when trailing benchmarks or trying to recover losses.

Part 3, Chapter 11 Summary: “Willpower? No Problem”

Thaler investigates the concept of self-control in economic decision-making, highlighting how traditional economic models often overlook human tendencies and behavioral quirks. The chapter begins with Thaler’s observation of a low-stakes poker game among Cornell faculty, where he noticed players’ decisions were influenced by whether they were winning or losing, despite the small amounts involved. This behavior was inconsistent with traditional economic theory, which assumes rational, consistent decision-making.

Thaler relates these observations to the broader context of mental accounting, where people treat money differently based on its source and their current financial state. He notes that when people are ahead financially, they tend to view the gains as “house money” and are more willing to take risks with it, illustrating a clear departure from the economic principle that money is fungible.

To further explore these concepts, Thaler and Eric Johnson conducted experiments to replicate these behaviors in a controlled setting. Their findings showed that people exhibited risk-seeking behavior when they perceived themselves as playing with “house money” or trying to break even. This insight into human behavior has implications for understanding financial markets, investment behaviors, and the psychology of gambling.

Part 3, Chapter 12 Summary: “The Planner and the Doer”

Thaler probes the complexities of self-control in economic decision-making, a topic that was relatively unexplored in economic literature at the time Thaler began his research. He references the work of economists and psychologists who have touched on self-control, such as Robert Strotz, Walter Mischel, and George Ainslie, to build his own understanding of the subject.

Thaler introduces the concept of the “Planner” and the “Doer” to explain self-control issues. The Planner is a forward-looking self, concerned with long-term well-being and making rational decisions for the future. In contrast, the Doer is impulsive, living for the present and often giving in to temptations. This dichotomy is used to model internal conflicts within individuals when making decisions that have implications both now and in the future.

Thaler and his colleague Hersh Shefrin developed a formal model to capture these interactions, employing a principal-agent framework commonly used in organizational theory. In this model, the Planner acts as the principal, setting rules and guidelines, while the Doer is the agent who must follow these rules but often seeks immediate gratification.

The model suggests self-control can be managed through commitment strategies (like Odysseus, Thaler suggests, binding himself to the mast to resist the Sirens) and by manipulating environmental factors (such as removing temptations from sight). However, these strategies can have limitations, such as inflexibility and the need for continual enforcement.

Part 3, Chapter 13 Summary: “Interlude: Misbehaving in the Real World”

Thaler discusses his practical experiences applying behavioral economics to real-world business challenges, focusing on two cases: Greek Peak, a ski resort near Ithaca, New York, and a consulting opportunity with General Motors.

At Greek Peak, Thaler used behavioral economics principles to address the ski resort’s financial struggles. He suggested gradually increasing lift ticket prices to avoid customer backlash and improve the overall skiing experience to justify the price hike. To cater to price-sensitive local markets, they introduced discounted pre-season ticket packages like the “ten-pack,” offering a mix of weekend and weekday passes at a significant discount. This strategy not only boosted early revenue, reducing the need for off-season borrowing, but also helped mitigate the risk of poor snowfall seasons. Thaler also found that only 60% of the pre-sold tickets were redeemed, effectively bringing in revenue at the full price.

Thaler’s consulting opportunity with General Motors (GM) revolved around their successful but poorly understood low-interest car loan promotion, which was outperforming the traditional cash rebate offers. Despite the success, GM did not have a clear understanding of why the promotion was so effective. Thaler’s visit to GM revealed a lack of analytical rigor in their marketing strategies, with no one responsible for evaluating the promotion’s success. He proposed that GM should thoroughly analyze why the promotion worked and plan for the future. However, GM declined his proposal, opting instead to focus on production planning to avoid excess inventory, a plan they failed to adhere to in subsequent years.

Parts 2-3 Analysis

The Human Factor in Economic Decision-Making gains further depth through Thaler’s concept of mental accounting. In Chapter 7, Thaler illustrates this with the dual concepts of acquisition and transaction utility. He uses the beer example, where people’s willingness to pay varies dramatically based on the purchase context, like a beach resort versus a grocery store. This differentiation challenges traditional economic views by incorporating psychological factors into consumer behavior, suggesting emotions and perceived value play significant roles in financial decisions.

Continuing with Challenging the Rationality Assumption, Thaler examines the concept of sunk costs and its irrationality in Chapter 8. He addresses the irrational behavior of individuals who let past investments affect current decisions, as in the case of Vince and his tennis elbow:

Vince paid $1,000 to an indoor tennis club that entitled him to play once a week for the indoor season. After two months he developed tennis elbow, which made playing painful. He continued to play in pain for three more months because he did not want to waste the membership fee. He only stopped playing when the pain became unbearable (85).

This demonstrates how past investments irrationally influence current decisions, highlighting a critical departure from rational economic behavior, which would dictate that past expenses should not affect present choices. Thaler’s discussion on sunk costs provides a clear example of how real-world decisions often deviate from the idealized, rational choices posited in traditional economic theory. He argues the irrational choices of humans must be considered in an understanding of markets.

Thaler highlights the theme of Behavioral Economics in Policy and Practice in Chapter 9, which discusses the application of mental accounting in household finance: “In those interviews with families [...] we learned that many households, especially those on a tight budget, used explicit budgeting rules” (97). He also highlights the real-life application of mental accounting, both for consumers and businesses, particularly how consumers seek transaction utility, enjoying the feeling of getting a good deal. Mental accounting is a concept that tangibly weds economics with the human element; it is economics in action, complete with accompanying psychology.

Thaler’s exploration of gambling psychology in Chapter 10 also probes the psychological nuances of risk-taking behavior. His scrutiny of poker games played by economists reveals that even those well-versed in theoretical rationality are influenced by the fluctuations of gains and losses: “Losing money in the poker account only changes behavior while you are still playing poker” (104). This observation accentuates the complex interplay between mental accounting and risk engagement, further questioning the presupposition of rationality in established economic theories.

In Chapters 11 and 12, Thaler infuses academic historical depth into the study of self-regulation within economics. His venture back into psychology in Chapter 12 exemplifies the cross-disciplinary essence of behavioral economics: “By the time I was thinking about self-control problems in 1978 [...] I turned to psychology for inspiration” (129). The Planner and Doer framework, conceived by Thaler, illuminates the internal tug-of-war in economic choices—where aspirations for the future often collide with immediate gratifications—elucidating the intricacies of self-discipline in routine financial decisions. Thaler used trends in psychology to develop this behavioralist perspective on economics.

When dissecting Utility, Thaler goes beyond the traditional boundaries of economic thought, recognizing the role of emotions, perceived worth, and psychological elements in sculpting economic actions and choices. This angle challenges the orthodox emphasis on utility maximization, introducing an additional layer of complexity to the process of making economic decisions. Human economic behavior, according to Thaler, cannot be understood in purely rationalist, utilitarian terms.

These chapters do more than critique established economic models; they underscore the imperative of incorporating human psychology into economic theories. Thaler’s blend of anecdotal narratives, empirical studies, and historical contexts stresses the significance of recognizing the human element, questioning established notions of rationality and translating these understandings into actionable policies and practices. An understanding of real-world economics has real-world uses.

blurred text
blurred text
blurred text
blurred text

Related Titles

By Richard H. Thaler