logo

60 pages 2 hours read

Richard H. Thaler

Misbehaving

Nonfiction | Book | Adult | Published in 2016

A modern alternative to SparkNotes and CliffsNotes, SuperSummary offers high-quality Study Guides with detailed chapter summaries and analysis of major themes, characters, and more.

Part 1Chapter Summaries & Analyses

Part 1, Chapter 1 Summary: “Supposedly Irrelevant Factors”

Content Warning: This guide quotes the author’s use of an offensive term about people with mental health conditions.

Thaler begins by recounting an experience from his early teaching career. He designed a challenging microeconomics exam intended to effectively differentiate students’ understanding levels. However, he faced unexpected backlash when students were upset over the average score being 72 out of 100. Thaler realized that despite explaining how these scores would translate into higher grades, the students’ dissatisfaction was unaffected. Their reaction was not in line with the rational behavior expected in economic models.

Thaler then decided to adjust his approach without simplifying the exam. He increased the total points to 137, making the average score appear higher—a 96—which significantly improved the students’ perception and satisfaction, although it didn’t change their actual grades. This incident exemplified how human behavior often deviates from the rational model assumed in economics.

Thaler uses this anecdote to introduce the concept of “misbehaving” in economics; he describes it as an instance in which human behavior contradicts the idealized, rational model of decision-making. He critiques the traditional economic model, which replaces real humans with the theoretical construct of “homo economicus” or “Econs.” Thaler argues that while this model is intellectually powerful and influential in policymaking, it fails to account for the complexities and biases inherent in human nature.

Throughout his career, Thaler explains, he observed various ways people diverge from the model of Econs, emphasizing that these deviations lead to inaccurate predictions and poor policy decisions. He advocates for an enriched approach to economic research that recognizes and incorporates human behavior, rather than relying solely on abstract models based on Econs.

Thaler’s narrative in this chapter sets the stage for exploring behavioral economics, a field that integrates psychology and other social sciences into economic theory. This approach not only enhances the accuracy of economic predictions but also makes the study of economics more relatable and engaging. Thaler’s storytelling illustrates the importance of considering “Supposedly Irrelevant Factors” (SIFs) in economic models, challenging the reader to rethink traditional economic theories in light of real-world human behavior.

Part 1, Chapter 2 Summary: “The Endowment Effect”

Thaler explores the divergence between traditional economic theory and human behavior, a theme that emerged during his graduate studies at the University of Rochester. Thaler’s journey begins with his thesis on “The Value of a Life” (26), where he attempts to quantify the monetary value people place on life and risk. He uses examples like Russian roulette to illustrate the complexity of determining the trade-off between money and the risk of death.

Central to this chapter is the concept of “willingness to pay” versus “willingness to accept” (28). Thaler discovers a significant discrepancy in how people value risk depending on whether they are avoiding it or accepting it. This finding contradicts the logical consistency and rational behavior predicted by economic models.

Thaler introduces the “endowment effect” through various anecdotes, such as a wine collector who values his own bottles more than their market price but is unwilling to buy or sell at that price. This effect demonstrates how people ascribe higher value to things they own compared to identical items they do not own, highlighting a disparity between perceived opportunity costs and actual expenses.

The chapter uses real-world examples, like ticket pricing for events, to show how the endowment effect influences decisions based on perceived costs. Thaler concludes by acknowledging the endowment effect’s challenge to conventional economic thought, emphasizing its role in understanding human decision-making’s irrational aspects.

Part 1, Chapter 3 Summary: “The List”

Thaler presents a series of real-life examples that challenge traditional economic theories of rational choice. These examples, which Thaler started compiling on a blackboard in his office, highlight the often-irrational behaviors of people in various everyday situations.

One example involves Thaler and a friend deciding not to attend a basketball game due to a snowstorm. They noted that if they had paid for the tickets, they would have gone despite the weather, illustrating the difficulty in ignoring sunk costs—costs that have already been incurred and cannot be recovered. Another instance describes a friend who refuses to pay someone to mow his lawn to avoid allergies; yet he wouldn’t mow another lawn for double the pay. This contradiction questions the economic principle that buying and selling prices should align.

Thaler also discusses Linnea, who considers driving to another store to save $10 on a $45 clock radio but would not do the same for a $10 discount on a $495 television. This inconsistency in valuing time challenges the notion of consistent valuation. Another example is Lee, he explains, who feels more comfortable receiving an expensive sweater as a gift from his wife than buying it himself, despite their shared finances. This scenario explores the concept of perceived value and decision-making in a shared economic unit.

Lastly, Thaler talks about removing a bowl of cashews during a dinner party to save guests’ appetites. This action goes against the economic idea that more choices are always better, highlighting how limiting options can sometimes be beneficial.

Part 1, Chapter 4 Summary: “Value Theory”

Thaler lays out the foundational concepts of what would later become known as Prospect Theory, developed by Daniel Kahneman and Amos Tversky. Thaler’s discovery of their work marked a turning point in his understanding of economic behavior, particularly in how people make decisions under uncertainty.

Thaler distinguishes between normative and descriptive theories. Normative theories describe how people should make decisions logically and consistently, much like the Pythagorean Theorem in geometry. Descriptive theories, on the other hand, aim to predict how people actually behave. Traditional economics often conflates these two, assuming people behave rationally as per normative models. Thaler illustrates this with an example involving the expansion of railroad tracks, where most people’s intuitive answers differ greatly from the correct mathematical solution.

Prospect Theory challenges this conventional approach by supplying a descriptive model of decision-making, particularly under conditions of uncertainty. It introduces the concept of a “value function,” which focuses on changes in wealth rather than absolute levels. This model recognizes that people experience diminishing sensitivity to both gains and losses and that they are more significantly affected by losses than gains (loss aversion).

Thaler comments on the simplicity and elegance of the value function graph, which captures key behavioral insights: People are risk-averse when it comes to gains but risk-seeking in the face of losses. This is due to the asymmetric nature of the value function, where the curve is steeper for losses than gains, showing losses are felt more intensely than equivalent gains.

Part 1, Chapter 5 Summary: “California Dreamin’”

Thaler narrates his journey to Stanford in the summer of 1977, driven by his growing interest in the intersection of psychology and economics. This period marks a pivotal time in Thaler’s career, as he begins to solidify his ideas about behavioral economics.

Thaler’s initial motivation for going to Stanford is to work with Sherwin Rosen on the value of life. However, learning Daniel Kahneman and Amos Tversky will be at Stanford in the fall, he seeks a way to extend his stay, intrigued by their work that inspired him. His persistence pays off when Victor Fuchs, the director of the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) office at Stanford, offers him a position funded through his grant.

During this period, Thaler’s interactions with Kahneman and Tversky are instrumental in shaping his thinking. He is fascinated by their approach to behavioral research, particularly their use of hypothetical scenarios to study decision-making. Thaler contrasts this with the skepticism of economists toward hypothetical questions, noting how Kahneman and Tversky’s research gradually gained acceptance due to its utility in explaining real-world behaviors.

Thaler reflects on his own research approach during this time, considering different methodologies, including experimental economics. He visits Vernon Smith and Charlie Plott, pioneers in the field, but remains unsure about fully committing to experimental economics. Thaler’s interest lies in studying behavior in various contexts, not limited to controlled experiments.

Part 1, Chapter 6 Summary: “The Gauntlet”

Thaler discusses the challenges he faced in introducing behavioral economics to a field dominated by traditional economic thinking. He outlines the skepticism and resistance he encountered from fellow economists, who were deeply invested in the prevailing models of rational choice and optimization.

Thaler describes a series of common objections, or “putdowns,” he often encountered when presenting his research. One such objection is the “as if” argument, suggesting that even if people are not capable of solving complex optimization problems, they behave as if they can. Thaler counters this by asserting that economic theories should apply to all people, not just experts, and that many real-life decisions do not offer the opportunity for the kind of learning and practice that would enable optimal decision-making.

Another objection he addresses is the belief in the power of incentives. Critics argued that higher stakes would lead people to make more rational decisions. However, Thaler points out that incentives alone are insufficient to ensure rational behavior, citing studies that showed increased stakes sometimes led to worse decision-making.

Thaler also tackles the argument that markets, through competitive forces, will correct irrational behaviors. He argues that while market forces do exert some influence, they cannot entirely counteract human irrationality. Businesses can survive and even thrive despite being poorly managed, and individuals often make irrational financial decisions.

Part 1 Analysis

Thaler challenges traditional economic theories by weaving together a narrative that underscores the complex, often irrational nature of human decision-making. This shift in perspective challenges the traditional economic narrative that often overlooks the nuanced realities of human behavior, opening new avenues for understanding economic phenomena.

Thaler highlights The Human Factor in Economic Decision-Making by recounting an anecdote from his teaching experiences. An incident involving the scoring of an exam reveals the often irrational yet predictable aspects of human behavior. Thaler notes:

Finally, an idea occurred to me. On the next exam, I made the total number of points available 137 instead of 100. This exam turned out to be slightly harder than the first, with students getting only 70% of the answers right, but the average numerical score was a cheery 96 points. The students were delighted! No one’s actual grade was affected by this change, but everyone was happy (14).

This simple manipulation, which left actual grades unaffected, reflects how human perception and satisfaction can be influenced by seemingly inconsequential factors. This episode exemplifies the divergence between human behavior and the rational models predicted by traditional economics, highlighting the significance of context and presentation in decision-making. This divergence from expected rational behavior underlines the importance of psychological factors in economic decisions, a theme Thaler revisits throughout his work.

In Chapter 2, Thaler introduces the “endowment effect,” a phenomenon where ownership alters perceived value, to demonstrate the psychological factor in economics. Thaler provides an example involving Dean Karlan, a graduate student in Chicago during Michael Jordan’s tenure with the Bulls. Karlan, along with a divinity school friend, faced a decision: attend a high-demand Bulls playoff game with gifted tickets, or sell them for a substantial profit. The divergence in their choices highlights the endowment effect. Karlan saw the tickets as a financial opportunity, while his friend, focusing on the “free” aspect, chose to enjoy the game. “Both Dean and his friend thought the other’s behavior was nuts,” Thaler writes (32). “Dean did not understand how his friend could possibly think he could afford to go to the game. His friend could not understand why Dean didn’t realize the tickets were free” (32). This episode epitomizes the endowment effect’s sway over decision-making—ownership transforms how people appraise items, frequently leading to illogical inclinations, thereby accentuating the book’s theme of Challenging the Rationality Assumption. Within a conventional economic paradigm, the worth of these tickets would hinge solely on their market price. However, Thaler’s illustration reveals how personal context and psychological proprietorship can drastically reshape perceived value, questioning standard economic presumptions about rationality.

While Thaler’s perspective injects novelty into economics, it also encounters skepticism from traditionalists—advocates of mathematical optimization and market efficiency—who downplay psychological insights. Detractors argue behavioral economics might disregard the self-correcting nature of markets and collective economic rationality. For instance, Merton Miller dismissed the significance of psychological factors in financial markets as being irrelevant to comprehending market dynamics. This standpoint maintains that despite individual irrationalities, overall market activity aligns with rational, profit-driven behavior. As Miller articulated, “That we abstract from all these narratives in constructing our models is not because the tales lack intrigue but because they may be too captivating, thus diverting attention from the fundamental market forces that ought to be our primary focus” (Sunstein, Cass R. “The Mischievous Science of Richard Thaler.” The New Rambler Review, 2015). This critique embodies a core contention within economics regarding the impact of individual behavioral quirks on wider market behaviors and decision-making processes. Traditionalists believe personal actions will ultimately be corrected and explained by more detached market forces.

In addressing Behavioral Economics in Policy and Practice, Thaler recounts how concepts like Prospect Theory—a framework that transformed the comprehension of decision-making under uncertainty—became integral to his methodology. This theory enabled him to integrate behavioral insights into tangible economic and policy applications. Thaler specifically confronts the “as if” hypothesis in economics, positing that even though individuals may struggle with complex problems, they act as though they are adept at navigating them. He refutes this by highlighting real-life instances where people’s choices markedly diverge from such idealized conduct. For example, Thaler observes that consumer purchase decisions are frequently swayed by emotions or misconceptions, rather than logical reasoning. This critique is vital, advocating for economic models that accurately mirror the intricate and flawed nature of human decision-making.

These opening chapters critique orthodox economic models, underscoring real-world behaviors that sharply contrast with predictions of rational economic theories. Thaler examines how market turbulence during financial crises often mirrors decisions driven by panic rather than well-informed responses to market data. This observation calls for a more sophisticated approach to economics—one that recognizes the impactful yet frequently overlooked influence of seemingly inconsequential factors and ingrained biases on human choices. Thaler’s proposition is more than a rethinking of economic theories; it’s a call to acknowledge the breadth of human nature in economic comprehension. His insights lay the groundwork for more precise and empathetic economic policies and practices, anchoring economic theory in the tangible realities of human behavior.

blurred text
blurred text
blurred text
blurred text

Related Titles

By Richard H. Thaler