62 pages • 2 hours read
Sven BeckertA modern alternative to SparkNotes and CliffsNotes, SuperSummary offers high-quality Study Guides with detailed chapter summaries and analysis of major themes, characters, and more.
As the new machines found in cotton mills boosted the productivity of the European cotton industry to unforeseen heights, the demand for raw cotton exploded in kind. At first, industrialists were at a loss as to where they would find the land and labor necessary to meet this demand. Despite the outsized role enslaved people in the Americas would soon play in supplying Europe with raw cotton, this solution was not immediately evident: “After all, in 1780 no cotton whatsoever arrived from North America” (85). The most obvious answer was to source raw cotton from India, but these plans were foiled by the East India Company which aggressively sought to protect its own manufacturing interests on the subcontinent.
Next, European industrialists looked to plantations in the Caribbean. Although these plantations traditionally focused on growing sugar, many smaller planters were easily convinced to grow cotton because it “drew on the labor of less than a fifth as many slaves as the average sugar plantation” (88). On British-controlled islands like Barbados, raw cotton exports quadrupled between 1781 and 1791. Similar gains were seen in French-controlled territories like Saint-Domingue. To supply the labor for these new plantations, a quarter million new enslaved Africans were imported between 1784 and 1791 alone. Beckert writes, “Slavery, in other words, was as essential to the new empire of cotton as proper climate and good soil” (91). The state also played a major role in the growth of cotton plantations in the Americas, in some cases offering free land to individuals who planted cotton in the West Indies: “By the 1780s, slaves in the West Indies and South America produced the vast majority of cotton sold on world markets” (94).
Unfettered access to raw cotton grown in Central and South America would not last, however. Many planters, having broken in the land with cotton for a few seasons, turned to sugar instead. Meanwhile, the 1791 revolt of enslaved people in Saint-Domingue halted exports of raw cotton from that island permanently. Of the momentous impact of this revolt, Beckert writes, “War capitalism had its first major reversal the hands of its seemingly least powerful actors” (96). Finally, once France declared war on Britain in 1793, access to cotton grown on French island colonies came to a decisive end. Despite these setbacks, Beckert writes that “a new way of producing cotton had been invented that focused clearly on plantations and slavery” (97), one that would soon take hold in the United States at an unprecedented scale.
Beckert writes that in the 1780s, “[i]t was all but unimaginable to Liverpool customs officials that cotton could be imported from the United States” (98). In the wake of cotton shortages resulting from the 1791 rebellion in Saint-Domingue, cotton farming exploded on the Atlantic coast of the Southern United States. Beckert writes, “Exports from South Carolina, for example, ballooned from less than 10,000 pounds in 1790 to 6.4 million pounds in 1800” (102). Production soon reached its limit, however. The variety these farmers grew, known as Sea Island cotton, failed to thrive at a substantial distance from the coast. While inland farmers were able to grow a different strain known as upland cotton, removing the seed from this variety was a slow and arduous process, severely limiting its potential. That changed in 1793 when the American engineer Eli Whitney invented a new kind of cotton gin capable of removing upland cotton seeds far more efficiently: “Overnight, his machine increased ginning productivity by a factor of fifty” (102).
In the inland Southern United States, a veritable cotton rush ensued, attracting cotton planters who brought with them tens of thousands of enslaved people, many of them newly brought over from Africa. Between 1790 and 1800, US cotton production increased from 1.5 million pounds annually to 36.5 million. By 1820, this number reached 167.5 million pounds, making up 32 percent of all US exports. Beckert writes, “It was on the back of cotton, and thus on the backs of slaves, that the U.S. economy ascended in the world” (119).
Even though Britain no longer directly participated in the enslavement trade, prohibiting it in 1807, its industrialists reaped the benefits of it to a colossal degree. Beckert writes, “While brutal coercion weighed like a nightmare upon millions of American slaves, the potential end of such violence was a nightmare to those who gathered the fabulous profits of the empire of cotton” (110). While plenty of Americans opposed slavery on moral grounds, Southern enslavers made up a powerful elite, exerting their control in state legislatures and the courts.
The need for more enslaved labor ran in parallel to the need for more land. After centuries of steady encroachment into Indigenous American territories, the territory owned by the United States nearly doubled overnight with the Louisiana Purchase in 1803, a purchase financed in part by wealthy British cotton merchants like Thomas Baring. Other instrumental land acquisitions included the purchase of Florida from Spain in 1819 and the annexation of Texas in 1845: “By 1850, 67 percent of U.S. cotton grew on land that had not been part of the United States half a century earlier” (105).
Owning these territories on paper meant nothing, however, without the might of the US military and its willingness to drive Indigenous inhabitants off the land. From the Chickasaw Nation in Tennessee to the Seminoles in Florida, the United States government expelled Indigenous Americans en masse to far less fertile land in Arkansas and Oklahoma. The US was often met with violent resistance, particularly from the Seminoles. Lasting from 1835 to 1842, the Seminole War was the longest military campaign in American history until the Vietnam War. Beckert writes, “The coercion and violence required to mobilize slave labor was matched only by the demands of an expansionist war against indigenous people” (108).
Beckert examines the uneven yet inexorable spread of mechanized cotton manufacturing throughout the world in the 19th century. Citing examples in continental Europe, the United States, and Mexico, Beckert argues that the strongest preconditions for cotton industrialization were “access to capital and a history in textile production” (148). Moreover, significant increases in low-cost British cotton imports all but forced non-mechanized industries to update their processes in order to survive. Beckert writes, “Though the British government tried to hold on to its monopoly, that technology spread rapidly due to active programs of private and government-directed industrial espionage as well as the unstoppable outflow of skilled British workers and cotton capitalists eager to make their fortunes in new lands” (152).
Also crucial to the project of industrialization was the role of the state: “What the British example also shows is the importance of the state’s capacity to forge conditions conducive to industrialization. Without a powerful state capable of legally, bureaucratically, infrastructurally, and militarily penetrating its own territory, industrialization was all but impossible” (155). Governments in France and Russia provided loans to budding industrialists in order to accelerate their gains in the cotton industry. As early as 1791, Alexander Hamilton published his “Report on the Subject of Manufactures,” urging the US government to support industrialization. In addition to loans and infrastructure investment, this support often took the form of state-mandated monopolies and protectionist tariffs and embargos: “Protectionism, once seen as a wartime cataclysm, now became a permanent feature of newly industrializing states” (158). Finally, for industrialization to thrive, the state needed to be sufficiently stable and strong to enforce property rights and contract laws. Meanwhile, in places like India where colonialism undermined state power, industrialization would not occur until the 1870s.
In examining why some countries succeeded in industrialization while others failed, Beckert looks to the example of Egypt. Eager to compete with European markets, Egypt’s ruler Muhammad Ali began to aggressively sponsor the project of cotton industrialization in 1815. By the 1830s, Egypt appeared to be following a similar trajectory as many successful European cotton industries, ranking fifth globally in cotton spindles per capita. Ali’s mistake, Beckert argues, is that he “followed the war capitalism model in Egypt itself” (168). While Europe effectively exported its war capitalism to US plantations and far-flung colonies, Ali employed enslaved Sudanese people and low-paid, tightly supervised Egyptians who worked under coerced conditions. By not paying its workers sufficient wages, Egypt’s domestic market was extremely limited. Moreover, Britain used its position of strength on the world stage to negotiate the opening of Egyptian markets to European goods, further decimating Egypt’s cotton industry and throwing the country off its course toward industrialization.
Beckert concludes, “Early industrialization depended, globally, on war capitalism, but in regions of the globe in which war capitalism took on its most violent edge cotton industrialization never resulted” (170). The exception, of course, was the United States, but so contrary were the local incentives of industrial societies versus plantation societies that it resulted in civil war.
As Beckert continues his exploration of the relationship between violence and commerce, it becomes clear that war capitalism was more than a mere precursor or prototype for industrial capitalism. Rather, the two fed off one another to an enormous degree. Nowhere is this clearer than in the dramatic rise in American plantations to meet the demand for raw cotton from Britain’s industrial cotton mills. In fact, despite the extent to which slavery and cotton are connected in the popular imagination, slavery only stepped in to meet these demands after industrialization had already begun in earnest in Britain: “As late as 1791, most of the cotton grown for manufacturing purposes around the world was produced by small farmers in Asia, Africa, and Latin America and consumed locally” (84). Thus, slavery—arguably the most pernicious form of war capitalism—was less a holdover from a pre-industrial era, and more a necessary feature of industrial capitalism that grew along with it. Beckert writes, “In the process, a new kind of slavery (what historians have called ‘second slavery’) emerged that was tightly linked to the intensity and profits of industrial capitalism” (92). This new form of slavery would also influence how non-slaveholding states would organize their own labor force. Beckert writes, “The all-encompassing control of workers—a core characteristic of capitalism—experienced its first great success on the cotton plantations of the American South” (115).
If slavery was not an immediately apparent solution to Britain’s demand for raw cotton, American slavery was even less so. Beckert writes that as late as 1785, “It was all but unimaginable to Liverpool customs officials that cotton could be imported from the United States” (98). The migration of cotton from Caribbean and South American plantations to the United States is an example of how political, social, environmental, and engineering factors all conspired to create a context in which America would become the top supplier of cotton to Europe’s industrialized societies. The interplay between these pressures is dizzying. For example, one of the most significant factors that led Britain to look to the United States as an ally in the cotton trade—despite having lost the American War of Independence to it in 1784—was the Haitian Revolution. In 1791, the enslaved people in the French colony of Saint-Domingue revolted in the largest successful rebellion of its kind in history. In addition to the immediate effect of cutting off the colony’s raw cotton supply to Britain, the rebellion called into question the conditions under which slavery was a sustainable model for cultivating raw materials. Of this momentous event, Beckert writes, “War capitalism had its first major reversal at the hands of its seemingly least powerful actors: Saint-Domingue’s hundreds of thousands of slaves” (96). Two years later, another major blow wrecked Caribbean cotton exports to Britain. Beckert writes, “Once war broke out between France and Britain in 1793, moreover, the import of French West Indian cottons into the British Caribbean ports came to an end” (97).
Wars and social upheavals weren’t the only factors that led Britain to look to the United States for cotton grown via slavery. While the Sea Island cotton grown in Saint-Domingue thrived on the coasts of the United States, it failed to thrive inland. While so-called upland cotton could be grown further inland, cultivating it was prohibitively time- and effort-intensive to the point that few plantation owners could make a profit off it. That all changed in 1793 when the American inventor Whitney invented a new kind of cotton gin well-suited to upland cotton, the only species that could be grown in an inland climate: “Overnight, his machine increased ginning productivity by a factor of fifty” (102). So it was that a war in Europe, a rebellion in Haiti, a stubborn cotton plant, and an engineering marvel all conspired to create the conditions under which American slavery would become the key driver of the industrial cotton manufacturing industry.
The connection between Whitney’s cotton gin and the expansion of American slavery is but one example of the relationship between technology and war capitalism. As America’s “cotton rush” continued unabated, more and more Indigenous land was expropriated to make room for plantations where enslaved Africans would be forced to participate in backbreaking labor. This process, Beckert argues, was only intensified by the advent of new technologies and inventions. He writes, “The first steamboats appeared on the Mississippi in 1817, reducing transport costs, and by the 1830s, railroads connected the new hinterland to river and seaports. The most modern technologies thus made the most brutal exploitation of human labor possible” (108). While technology is often framed as evidence of society’s progress, Beckert recasts these inventions of agents of suffering—after all, the more efficient cotton’s global commodity chains became, the greater appetite for expropriated Indigenous land and enslaved labor to meet the demand for raw cotton, the lifeblood of the entire system.
A virtually unlimited supply of land and labor, obtained through violence and coercion, was of course a crucial factor in America’s ascent to become the world’s leading cotton producer. Another, Beckert argues, was the political power of Southern elites. Perhaps the most significant example of Southern political power at work was the Three-Fifths Compromise, agreed to in 1787 at the United States Constitutional Convention. Because enslaved people were not initially given rights by the US Constitution, Northern delegates argued that they should not be counted as citizens for the purpose of determining the number of seats Southern states would receive in Congress. In the end, Southern delegates convinced their counterparts to count enslaved people as three-fifths of a person when tabulating state populations and allocating Congressional states. This gave Southerners, and in particular Southern enslavers, an outsized influence over national political affairs. Beckert writes, “Southern slaveholders had enshrined the basis of their power into the Constitution with its three-fifths clause. A whole series of slaveholding presidents, Supreme Court judges, and strong representation in both houses of Congress guaranteed seemingly never-ending political support for the institution of slavery” (111).
While slavery has been abolished in the United States since the American Civil War, debates over Southerners’ attempts to enshrine the institution of slavery in the US Constitution persist to this day. For example, Beckert points out that one of the reasons slavery seemed more durable in the United States than in Saint-Domingue was because of white militias. He writes, “Americans tried to explain to their European customers that slavery in the United States, unlike in Saint-Domingue, was safe—not least, as [American statesman] Tench Coxe put it, because of the presence of a powerful white militia and because slaves have ‘no artillery nor arms’” (122). Modern legal scholars like law professor Carl T. Bogus have argued that the Second Amendment was written specifically to empower white people in Southern states to arm themselves against potential revolts by the enslaved population (Bogus, Carl T. “The Hidden History of the Second Amendment.” U.C. Davis Law Review, vol. 31, 1998). While there is some evidence in the historical record supporting this claim, several contemporary American conservatives dispute it. Nevertheless, it reflects the extent to which the very specific debates between American statesmen and British industrialists in the 1800s over cotton are still relevant in American political culture today. Moreover, it reveals how deeply slavery is embedded into the economic, political, and social history of the United States.